Government Formation in Parliamentary Democracies
In: Party Governance and Party Democracy, S. 13-31
27 Ergebnisse
Sortierung:
In: Party Governance and Party Democracy, S. 13-31
In: Pacific affairs, Band 81, Heft 1, S. 125-126
ISSN: 0030-851X
In: Journal of east Asian studies, Band 5, Heft 2, S. 354-356
ISSN: 2234-6643
In: European journal of political research: official journal of the European Consortium for Political Research. Political data yearbook, Band 53, Heft 1, S. 189-197
ISSN: 2047-8852
In: Studies in comparative international development: SCID, Band 49, Heft 1, S. 44-66
ISSN: 1936-6167
In: International studies quarterly: the journal of the International Studies Association, Band 58, Heft 4, S. 828-838
ISSN: 1468-2478
In: European Journal of Political Research Political Data Yearbook, Band 52, Heft 1, S. 121-133
In: European journal of political research: official journal of the European Consortium for Political Research. Political data yearbook, Band 51, Heft 1, S. 167-174
ISSN: 2047-8852
In: American journal of political science: AJPS, Band 52, Heft 4, S. 926-941
ISSN: 0092-5853
In: The journal of legislative studies, Band 10, Heft 2-3, S. 250-262
ISSN: 1743-9337
In: Japan and North America: RoutledgeCurzon library of modern Japan Vol. 1
In: Japan and North America: RoutledgeCurzon library of modern Japan Vol. 2
In: Journal of peace research, Band 55, Heft 6, S. 726-741
ISSN: 1460-3578
Developing states furnish the vast majority of UN peacekeeping troops, a fact academics and policymakers often attribute (at least partly) to developing states' supposed ability to derive a profit from UN peacekeeping reimbursements. In this article, we argue that this 'peacekeeping for profit' narrative has been vastly overstated. The conditions for significantly profiting from UN peacekeeping are in fact highly restrictive, even for developing states. We begin by highlighting two potent reasons for re-examining the peacekeeping for profit narrative: developing states emerged as the UN's principal troop contributors in a period of stagnant reimbursement rates when UN peacekeeping was becoming less financially attractive; and the quantitative evidence scholars have presented as supporting the peacekeeping for profit narrative is flawed. We then identify the scope conditions within which peacekeeping for profit provides a plausible explanation for a developing state's UN troop contributions. First, the deployment and its attendant reimbursements must be significant not only in absolute and per-soldier terms but also in relation to the state's total armed forces and military expenditure. Second, the state must have an exceptional ability, compared with other troop contributors, to benefit from UN reimbursements. The scope for generalized profit-making from either equipment or personnel contributions is limited by intense political pressure against reimbursement rate increases. Individual states can nevertheless make a profit if they (1) invest in inexpensive and old but functional equipment, especially if deployed with usage restrictions, and/or (2) limit the deployment allowances (rather than salaries) they pay their peacekeepers. We establish that only a limited subset of developing states meets the plausibility conditions for the peacekeeping for profit narrative – and many top UN troop contributors do not.
World Affairs Online
In: American journal of political science, Band 52, Heft 4, S. 926-941
ISSN: 1540-5907
When do politicians resort to corrupt practices? This article distinguishes between two types of corruption by politicians: illegal acts for material gain (looting) and illegal acts for electoral gain (cheating). Looting generally involves a politician "selling" influence while cheating involves a politician "buying" votes. Individual‐level analyses of new data on financial scandals and election law violations in Japan show that the determinants of cheating differ from the determinants of looting. Most notably, political experience and electoral security increase the probability of looting, but electoral insecurity combined with intraparty competition increases the probability of cheating.
In: British journal of political science, Band 35, Heft 2, S. 357-368
ISSN: 1469-2112
Both academics and journalists have given increasing attention to the rising importance of prime ministers – a phenomenon often referred to 'presidentialization'. Although many commentators use the term differently, and the term blurs the line between the very different institutional contexts of a parliamentary and presidential system, one careful definition of the term is 'the movement over time away from collective to personalized government, movement away from a pattern of governmental and electoral politics dominated by the political party towards one where the party leader becomes a more autonomous political force.'This phenomenon has been observed primarily in Britain and in West European parliamentary democracies – no one has ever described the Japanese parliamentary system as even remotely 'presidentialized'. In fact, the Japanese prime minister has not been the subject of much academic research, and even the Japanese press often used to ignore the prime minister. Despite being the leader of a majority party in a centralized political system, the Japanese prime minister was almost universally described as weak and uninteresting, with both academic and popular discourse focusing on the powerful bureaucracy and factional politics within the Liberal Democratic Party (LDP). However, recent political changes, most prominently the selection and popularity of Junichirō Koizumi as Japan's prime minister in the spring of 2001, have led to a surge of interest in the prime minister.