American Treasure and the price revolution in Spain, 1501-1650
In: Harvard economic studies 43
31 Ergebnisse
Sortierung:
In: Harvard economic studies 43
In: Harvard economic studies 81
In: Harvard Economic Studies 51
In: The journal of economic history, Band 37, Heft 1, S. 13-19
ISSN: 1471-6372
Wars in early modern times, although frequent, generated little price inflation because of their limited demands on real resources. The invention of paper currency and the resort to deficit financing to pay for wars changed that situation. In recent centuries wars have been the principal causes of inflation, although since World War II programs of social welfare unmatched by offsetting taxation have also fueled inflationary flames.
In: History of political economy, Band 1, Heft 1, S. 123-149
ISSN: 1527-1919
In: The journal of economic history, Band 12, Heft 4, S. 325-349
ISSN: 1471-6372
It May have been the ingrained pessimism of Bentham and McCulloch that provoked Carlyle to dub economics the dismal science. It surely must have been economists' concern over price theory, which they regarded and still regard as the central core of economics, that made the name stick. Studies of the role of prices in history are no less tedious and technical than price theory, and in hands no more skillful than mine they can be even more dreary. But this is not the worst of my worries. The evidence that I shall sketch supports the pessimistic hypothesis that during certain germinal periods price and wage behavior of the type that is now taking a distressing percentage of real income from all of us who live on our salaries has proved beneficial to society in the long run and that the type of price and wage behavior which would benefit most of us in the short run has had serious disadvantages. Yet I have the inner satisfaction of appearing to be objective in my thinking and fearless in airing my conclusions in a gathering of some of the worst aggrieved.
In: Journal of political economy, Band 57, Heft 4, S. 315-336
ISSN: 1537-534X
In: Journal of political economy, Band 57, Heft 2, S. 134-156
ISSN: 1537-534X
In: The journal of economic history, Band 6, Heft 1, S. 73-79
ISSN: 1471-6372
In: Journal of political economy, Band 54, Heft 2, S. 116-140
ISSN: 1537-534X
In: Journal of political economy, Band 54, Heft 1, S. 17-37
ISSN: 1537-534X
In: Journal of political economy, Band 53, Heft 2, S. 97-114
ISSN: 1537-534X
In: The journal of economic history, Band 4, Heft S1, S. 47-60
ISSN: 1471-6372
The prices of commodities and wages of labor recorded in contemporaneous account books are the oldest continuous objective economic data in existence. Economic historians have not neglected this great intellectual resource. In fact, during the last hundred years a large proportion of the outstanding economic and historical talent has been lavished upon price history. Tooke, D'Avenel, and Rogers devoted more than twenty-five years each, at the most productive stage of their careers, to collecting price and wage statistics from manuscript sources and to writing an impressive total twenty-odd learned volumes. In the present century Beveridge in England, Elsas in Germany, Posthumus in the Netherlands, Pribram in Austria, Bujak in Poland, Bezanson and Cole in the United States, and a host of lesser lights on both sides of the Atlantic have uncovered new sources, combed old ones more exhaustively, and employed modern statistical technique to give us relatively complete and refined histories of prices in the leading economic areas of the Western world in modern times. If the old records of commercial transactions are not destroyed in total war, it seems safe to assume that future generations of scholars, seeking light from the past on recurrent inflation and deflation, will produce price histories that surpass all studies yet written in historical range, completeness, and scientific accuracy. In view of these achievements and prospects, social scientists should ask themselves what can be gained from a proper utilization of price history and what losses may result from its misuse.
In: The journal of economic history, Band 4, Heft 1, S. 21-48
ISSN: 1471-6372
The sixteenth-century Price Revolution in Spain induced by the gigantic stream of Mexican and Peruvian silver was followed by a century of alternate inflation and deflation resulting from wars and weak governments. But in spite of frequent, long, and unsuccessful wars, monetary stability characterized the first half of the eighteenth century. Then a sharp rise in the output of the precious metals, particularly of Mexican silver, increased the Spanish monetary stock and forced prices upward by almost one third in the next three decades of comparative peace. To finance a bitter conflict with England in 1779–83, Spain was compelled to resort to her first issues of paper money. The paper currency depreciated rapidly during the war but rose to par after the conclusion of peace and remained there throughout the Nootka Sound controversy.