On the "Chicago School of Economics"
In: Journal of political economy, Band 70, Heft 1, S. 64-69
ISSN: 1537-534X
6772811 Ergebnisse
Sortierung:
In: Journal of political economy, Band 70, Heft 1, S. 64-69
ISSN: 1537-534X
In: ASU Center for the Study of Economic Liberty Research Paper
SSRN
Working paper
In: Journal of political economy, Band 70, Heft 1, S. 70-71
ISSN: 1537-534X
In: Social studies of science: an international review of research in the social dimensions of science and technology, Band 44, Heft 4, S. 489-517
ISSN: 1460-3659
In recent years, science studies scholars have critically examined several methods used by the pharmaceutical industry to exert control over knowledge about drugs. Complementary literatures on 'medical neoliberalism' and 'neoliberal science' draw attention to the economic ideas justifying such methods of organizing knowledge, and in so doing suggest that neoliberal thinkers may play an important role in developing them. As yet, the nature of this role remains unexplored. Relying on heretofore-unexamined archival evidence, this article establishes a direct link between the Chicago School of Economics and the mobilization of the pharmaceutical industry in the 1970s. It argues that economists affiliated with the Chicago School of Economics sought to influence pharmaceutical policy and science and constructed institutions to do so. These institutions – most notably the Center for the Study of Drug Development – remain highly influential. This article contributes to a historical understanding of how neoliberal ideas came to assume prominence in pharmaceutical policy, the management of science, and scientific practice.
In: Indes: Zeitschrift für Politik und Gesellschaft, Band 7, Heft 1, S. 107-114
ISSN: 2196-7962
SSRN
Working paper
In: Modern intellectual history: MIH, Band 14, Heft 2, S. 507-535
ISSN: 1479-2451
This article examines the role of the consumer in the writings on regulation launched by the Chicago school from the 1930s to the 1980s. It shows how Chicago school scholars used the concept of the consumer to shape and justify their calls for deregulation, as they continually claimed to offer market solutions that protect and benefit the consumer. The focus is on how the scholars at issue executed a shift from choice to welfare in their consumer concept as they began more decisively to embrace deregulation in the postwar period. From initially having described consumers as individual agents, capable of ensuring democracy and freedom in modern society by expressing their choices on a partly regulated market, they began to portray consumers as a coherent, homogeneous and predictable mass, acting on a deregulated market and serving merely as a tool of so-called consumer welfare, understood as economic efficiency and aggregate wealth.
In: Ikonomičeska misăl, Band 67, Heft 4, S. 452-472
ISSN: 2815-3189
George Josef Stigler is known as the scientist who strongly influenced the formation of the Chicago School of Economics. He promoted the idea of expanding price theory beyond the boundaries of economics and developed it into a universal model for the analysis of human behaviour, known as the economic approach to human behaviour. His research inspired the Public Choice literature and the Economic Theory of Law. Besides, Stigler made numerous contributions which nowadays are integral parts of economic theory. In this essay we summarize some of Stigler's outstanding contributions, particularly his work on information economics and the economic theory of regulation.
In: History of political economy, Band 45, Heft 2, S. 345-349
ISSN: 1527-1919
In: Journal of the history of economic thought, Band 46, Heft 2, S. 169-200
ISSN: 1469-9656
Though the Chicago school has been the subject of no small amount of research over the past several decades, that scholarship has focused largely on persons, ideas, and influence—in short, on the school itself. No attention has been paid to the origins of that label and the avenues via which the notion of a "Chicago school" of economics came to be. This paper attempts to address that lacuna, drawing on both published and archival resources. What emerges is a story of a label of uncertain origin but wrapped up in competing agendas, the first stage in the history of which culminates in 1962 with its rejection by two of the very people who helped birth it.
In: Archival Insights into the Evolution of Economics Ser.
Intro -- Contents -- Chronology -- Part I Hayek's Luck -- 1 'I Have Been Lucky in This Game' -- 1 'Von' Hayek's Luck -- 2 Producer Sovereignty -- 3 Property: 'Reflections on Becoming an Austrian Economist and Staying One' -- 4 The Four Gospels -- 5 Chicago and Their Austrian 'Other Half': Repulsive Attraction -- 6 Volume Overview -- Archival Insights into the Evolution of Economics (and Related Projects) -- 2 The Tobacco, Obesity and Fossil Fuel Lobby-'As Happy as Hell' -- 1 An Overview of the Argument Plus Indirect Test (1) -- 2 Indirect Test (2) -- 3 Indirect Test (3) -- 4 Indirect Test (4) -- Archival Insights into the Evolution of Economics (and Related Projects) -- 3 1-15: Residual Reverence Towards the Second Estate -- 1 Recruitment to the London School of Economics -- 2 'Free' Market 'Intellectuals': Recruitment Through 'Specious' Visions -- Bibliography -- 4 16-20: Loyal 'Intermediaries' -- 1 Robbins and Machlup, Knight and Viner -- 2 Knight: A Second Chicago Oral Tradition? -- 3 Schmidt and Berger -- Archival Insights into the Evolution of Economics -- 5 21-24: 'I Desire to Preserve Correct Relations in Public' -- 1 Kaldor, Scitovsky and Thomas -- 2 Galbraith and 'Knowledge' Communities -- 3 Keynes, Sraffa, Kahn and Joan Robinson -- 4 Friedman's Prediction of Stagflation -- 5 Slum Dwellers -- 6 'Not a Matter of a Simple Defence of a Liberal System of Society': Austrians and the Eternal 'Merit' of 'Fascism' -- References -- 6 25: Suppression, the Dogs That Didn't Bark and the Emerging Chicago School of Economics -- 1 Suppression -- 2 Dogs That Didn't Bark -- 3 Non-recruitment to the University of Chicago Department of Economics -- 4 Hayek Mark I and Hayek Mark II? -- Archival Insight into the Evolution of Economics (and Related Projects) -- 7 31 Conclusions About Hayek's Nineteen Thirty-One 'Prediction'.
SSRN
In: Archival insights into the evolution of economics
On 9 August 1974, Richard Nixon resigned to avoid impeachment; on 29 April 1975, the United States scuttled from their Embassy in Saigon - optics that were interpreted as defeats for the 'International Right'. Yet in 1975, Margaret Thatcher became leader of the Conservative Party; and in 1976 Ronald Reagan almost unseated a sitting Republican Party President. Pivotal to the 'turn to the Right' was Friedrich 'von' Hayek's 1974 Nobel Prize for Economic Science - awarded for having used Austrian Business Cycle Theory to predict the Great Depression: 'For him it is not a matter of a simple defence of a liberal system of society as may sometimes appear from the popularized versions of his thinking.' The evidence suggests that Hayek's fraudulent assertion was uncovered at the University of Chicago in the early 1930s - but not reported. The most likely explanation is self-censorship - for reasons of ideological correctness, fund raising and residual deference to the Second Estate. Four indirect tests suggest that 'free' market economists have - in other instances and presumably for fund-raising motives - suppressed embarrassing 'knowledge': which suggests that they were perfectly capable of suppressing 'knowledge' about Hayek's non-prediction of the Great Depression. With respect to the Nobel Prize and thus his ability to reach a wider audience, Hayek was fortune in having two loyal 'intermediaries': Lionel Robbins and Fritz Machlup who were - and probably felt themselves to be - 'socially' inferior to 'von' Hayek.--
In: Archival insights into the evolution of economics