Econometric Analysis of Birth Rate Dynamics in Britain
In: The journal of human resources, Band 23, Heft 4, S. 563
ISSN: 1548-8004
5608 Ergebnisse
Sortierung:
In: The journal of human resources, Band 23, Heft 4, S. 563
ISSN: 1548-8004
In: Journal of biosocial science: JBS, Band 2, Heft 3, S. 283-292
ISSN: 1469-7599
In: The American journal of sociology, Band 49, Heft 2, S. 149-155
ISSN: 1537-5390
In: Population and development review, Band 12, S. 196
ISSN: 1728-4457
In: Australian quarterly: AQ, Band 9, Heft 2, S. 51
ISSN: 1837-1892
In: Izvestiya of Altai State University
In: European view: EV, Band 7, Heft 2, S. 225-236
ISSN: 1865-5831
This article provides an overall survey of Europe's demographic patterns and statistics. It identifies economic progress, institutional modernisation, and development of the welfare state as factors contributing to fertility shifts and particularly to postponement of childbearing. The authors suggest Europe needs policies aimed at demographic renewal which focus first on diminishing direct costs borne by both parents and second, on diminishing indirect costs born predominantly by women. If Europe can effect the necessary paradigm shifts in gender roles and society it will prepare the way for holistic solutions.
In: Journalism quarterly, Band 58, Heft 4, S. 633-635
In: Population and environment: a journal of interdisciplinary studies, Band 46, Heft 1
ISSN: 1573-7810
AbstractUsing data from 32 European countries for nearly 244 million live births between 1969 and 2021, this paper examines the effects of temperatures on birth rates. The results show that exposure to hot days slightly reduces birth rates five to eight months later, while much stronger negative effects are observed nine to ten months after exposure to hot temperatures. Thereafter, a partial recovery is observed, with slightly increased birth rates. This study also shows that the effect of high-humidity hot days is much stronger than that of hot days with low humidity. Besides, the effect of heatwave days has been found to be more severe than that of hot days that are not preceded by other hot days. This study finds that some adaptation to heat might be expected only in the long run.
In: European view: EV, Band 7, Heft 2, S. 209-216
ISSN: 1865-5831
The paper reviews recent demographic changes in Europe and puts particular focus on declining birth rates. It is argued that recent demographic patterns are largely driven by changing attitudes and a reorientation of values, but that lack of government support is an important reason why actual demographic behaviour varies across countries. Interestingly, new and modern forms of demographic behaviour, such as cohabitation, out-of-wedlock childbearing and divorce are also associated with higher birth rates, and it is argued that government support and the way welfare provision is organised play a crucial role.
In: European view: EV, Band 7, Heft 2, S. 333-340
ISSN: 1865-5831
While the European Union recognises the importance of ageing and falling populations in a number of official documents, the findings require focus. In this article, the author first identifies the documents' failure to name a target birth rate. Second, he stresses that the often mentioned fertility level of an average of 1.5 children per woman underestimates the real figure. Thirdly, he points out the futility of fertility policies when ageing processes will continue regardless of birth rate changes. In response, policies must be coordinated in a number of areas including gender policy, employment policy, immigration policy, housing policy, family policy and economic policy.
In: Vestnik Instituta vostokovedenija RAN: Journal of the Institute of Oriental Studies RAS, Heft 2 (28), S. 73-85
In: U.S. news & world report, Band 64, S. 64-65
ISSN: 0041-5537
In: Population and development review, Band 27, Heft 4, S. 781-789
ISSN: 1728-4457
Continuing below‐replacement fertility and projected declines in population size are demographic features of many European countries and Japan. They are variously met with complacent acceptance, calls for higher rates of immigration, or—often last and least—proposals for increasing the birth rate. Fertility was also low in the 1930s, and some of the policy debate from that period resonates today. In England and Wales, fertility then had been declining for half a century. Over the decade 1931–40, it averaged 1.8 children per woman—moreover, with net emigration. Worries over this situation and its likely consequences led to the setting up in 1944 of a Royal Commission on Population, charged with considering "what measures, if any, should be taken in the national interest to influence the future trend in population." In a memorandum submitted to the Commission in that year, the economist R. F. Harrod set out a detailed proposal to encourage childbearing through a scheme of family endowments. Part of the introductory section of Harrod's submission, arguing the case for state intervention and for material rather than 'spiritual' measures, is reproduced below.An evident problem in offering economic incentives for childbearing is that, to induce a given behavioral change, well‐off families would require much larger incentives than the poor. Hence child endowments that aspire to effectiveness across the income distribution have to be skewed toward the upper end. Harrod argues that this is as it should be, that policy should establish neutrality between large and small family sizes, and that this is a conceptually separate issue from poverty alleviation. 'We should seek a re‐distribution of national income favourable to the parents of larger families and the plan should be put into effect whether or not another re‐distribution as between rich and poor is proceeding at the same time.' He remarks on the implausibility of the government's being able to 'talk up' fertility— thereby generating some kind of costless ideational change, a 'spiritual aufklärung.'Later pans of the submission not reprinted here cover the specific details of the proposal. The proposed annual benefit per child (intended for every child after the second, with half‐rates payable for the second child) is paid for 18 years. It is substantial and increases with the child's age—at ages 13–18, for most of the income range it amounts to 20–30 percent of the father's income (or mother's, if hers is higher). Harrod also discusses further the rationale for making the endowments (and the compulsory contributions—a flat 5 percent of income—that finance them) proportional to income. To make his case Harrod draws on the dysgenic and population‐quality arguments popular at the time: worry about 'race decline' and 'a general lowering of standards and of efficiency if the parents who are best equipped in experience, knowledge and culture are relatively infertile.'In the event, the Commission recommended a flat schedule of family allowances, together with tax exemptions for dependent children calculated to provide some income‐based benefit. These were justified on population as well as equity and welfare grounds, 'since the handicaps of parenthood have played a large part in the fall of average family size below replacement level.' Population quality issues—the subject of several other submissions—were sidestepped by calling for further research. By the time the Commission's report was finally published, in 1949, the baby boom was well underway: average fertility over 1946–50 was 2.4.Roy Forbes Harrod (1900–78) was one of the foremost economists of his day. His career was largely spent at Christ Church College, Oxford. A student and sometime colleague of Keynes, his best‐known early work was centered on identifying a dynamic equilibrium growth path for the economy—building on Keynes's static equilibrium analysis. As stylized (by others), this came to be called the Harrod‐Domar growth model, a formulation basic to growth theory. Harrod was editor of the Economic Journal for the period 1945–66. He was active in politics and as an economic adviser to both Labour and Conservative governments. He was knighted in 1959.The extract is reprinted from volume 5 of the Papers of the Royal Commission on Population (London: His Majesty's Stationery Office, 1950), pp. 80–85.